[Part I of
the "Free Enterprise" midterm question]
BUSINESS AND
INDUSTRY IN THE LATE 19TH CENTURY
FREE ENTERPRISE?
KEY TERMS: CREDIT MOBILIER, ERIE WAR, CARNEGIE, J.P.
MORGAN, ROCKEFELLER, KNIGHTS
OF LABOR, HAYMARKET RIOT, A.F.L., HOMESTEAD STRIKE, PULLMAN RIOTS,
EUGENE DEBS, SHERMAN ANTITRUST ACT
American Economic Growth 1865-1900
The late 19th century was a time of phenomenal growth in business
and
industry. GNP increased by 600% between 1865 and 1900. The
population of the country doubled, a sign of healthy, vibrant
economy. We went from 35,000 miles of rails to over 160,000
miles during this period. We had more miles of track
than all of Europe combined. There was tremendous growth in
oil,
coal, steel—just about everything associated with
industrialization.
Along with this growth came all the problems typically associated
with
industrialization. Both the blessings and the problems or
industrialization are often attributed to the "free enterprise"
system,
a system where government maintains a laissez-faire attitude
toward
business and economics. But it is doubtful if the economic
system
of the late 19th century can truly be characterized as one of
"free
enterprise."
The Tariff
Throughout this period, the competition that should be the heart
of a
free enterprise system was limited by a high protective tariff on
imported goods, generally 40-50% of the value of those
goods. The
tariff meant that a disproportionate share of the cost of
government
was paid for by those who might have consumed foreign goods or
gotten
American goods cheaper. Farmers in general and the South in
particular were adversely affected by the tariff.
Railroads
The growth of American rails is another example of government
intervention on the behalf of business rather than a truly
free-market
system.
The Federal government, for instance, gave huge subsidies to the
companies that built
the first transcontinental railroad, Union Pacific and Central
Pacific.
These companies got 20 square miles of land for each mile of track
laid,
plus direct payments of $16,000 and $48,000 per mile for track
laid in
plain areas and mountain areas respectively.
Not content with their enormous government-subsidized profits, the
directors of Union Pacific maximized their own profits by hiring
out
the work to a subsidiary, Credit Mobilier. They paid Credit
Mobilier $73
million for $50 million worth of work. Why? Well, they
controlled Credit Mobilier outright while they were only major
share holders in
Union Pacific. The scheme they adopted allowed them to
transfer
$23,000,000 in profits directly to themselves so that they would
not
have to share with the other Union Pacific stock holders.
The directors of Central Pacific (Stanford, Huntington, Crocker,
and
Hopkins) did likewise, raking in the big bucks and ensuring bright
futures in business and politics for themselves. Meanwhile,
those
doing the actual work (engineers like Theodore Judah and the Irish
“Paddies” and Chinese “Coolies” who did the actual work) received
little credit or compensation.
Ultimately, the Federal government gave away more than 155 million
acres of land to the railroads—and local governments gave the
railroads
even more so that the rails would go through their town rather
than
some other.
Why did local governments do this? Not much choice.
Columbia (just to the Northeast of Aberdeen), was at first the
bigger town. But Columbia civic official refused to be easy
marks for the railroads. The railroad owners were annoyed,
so they changed routes. Aberdeen became "The Hub City," and
Columbia faded.
When not ripping off stockholders and the government, the railroad
tycoons were busy ripping each other off and destroying
competition. Cornelius Vanderbilt, for instance, decided to
secretly buy up Erie Railroad stock so he could control the line
and
eliminate its tendency to compete with his own lines. The
directors of
the Erie (Jay Gould, Dan Drew, and Jim Fisk) figured out what he
was
doing and responded by watering the stock: printing more and more
shares so that Vanderbilt wouldn’t gain control no matter how many
shares he bought. Ultimately, there was $74 million of
outstanding stock on a railroad worth perhaps $24 million.
Fisk,
Gould, and Drew pocketed the difference, not using the money for
capital improvements or anything else to improve the value of the
company. These men pocketed millions—while the other Erie
stockholders made nothing at all. The railroad didn’t pay a
dividend
for 70 years, and its safety record was the worst in the
country—in an
era when trains were notoriously unsafe anyway.
Further, railroad companies in general connived to make sure there
was
no real competition among them, forming “pools." The "pools"
were essentially agreements not to compete so that prices and
profits could remain
high. “The public be damned,” said William H.
Vanderbilt.
The Steel (Steal?) Industry
The growth of the railroads meant a tremendous increase in the
demand
for steel, and more opportunity for enterprising
individuals. One
of the biggest names in steel: Andrew Carnegie.
Carnegie’s story is often used as a model of the American
ideal.
Young Andrew, son of a tailor, emigrated from Scotland, working as
a
bobbin boy for $1.20 a day. Honest, industrious, and
hard-working, always willing to do the extra job, he accumulated
enough
capital to buy his way into the steel business. One of the
first
to see the potential of the Bessemer process to turn out a higher
quality steel at a lower price, Carnegie ended up earning a large
fortune—which he then prepared to give away. His “gospel of
wealth” said that the man who died rich died disgraced, and so
Carnegie
used his money to endow schools, libraries, etc.
Well, that’s the way free-enterprise is supposed to work, and the
story
above is basically true…but it’s not the whole truth.
The Bessemer process was *first* used in this country by Duquesne
Steel, not Carnegie. Carnegie knew who wasn’t going to be able to
compete with Duquesne, a company turning out a better product and
a
lower price. So he wrote to the railroad companies and
warned
them that Bessemer steel was dangerous: they were going to face
accidents and law suits if they used it. Duquesne found
itself
losing contract after contract. Its stock price
plummeted—and
Carnegie made his move. He bought up control of Duquesne at
a
bargain price—and now he improved Bessemer steel. Oh, the
steel
wasn’t actually any different: but there was a big improvement:
now
Carnegie-controlled mills were producing it!
Carnegie further increased his competitive advantage by mastering
what’s called vertical integration: controlling the manufacture of
steel at every step. He controlled iron mines, coal mines,
rails,
enabling him to control production costs and undercut his
competitors.
J.P. Morgan, another manufacturing of steel was unhappy with the
competition and the downward pressure on steel prices, so he
simply
bought Carnegie out, paying Carnegie $500 million more than
Carnegie’s
company was really worth. But, for Morgan, ending completion
worked out just fine. His company, Unite States Steel,
became the
first billion dollar company in America, maybe the world.
Morgan also had his hand in the railroad industry and in
banking.
As in steel, he worked to eliminate completion and to keep profits
up. He didn’t have to buy up control, either. Other
businessmen were ready to join him to create what were called
trusts,
agreements to limit competition and keep prices high.
Eventually,
there were trusts in all sorts of different industries, trusts
that
eliminated the competition necessary for a truly free enterprise
system. And then there were the outright monopolies such as
the
oil monopoly created by John D. Rockefeller.
Rockefeller and his Standard Oil Company were completely
unscrupulous
in the way they dealt with potential competitors. For instance,
Rockefeller might buy up all the barrel staves in an area so
competitors couldn’t get barrels to ship their oil.
But Rockefeller’s most successful tactic was the one he used with
the
railroads. “You want my business?” he asked, “Well, then,
give me
a rebate on each barrel I ship with you—oh, and I also want a
rebate on
each barrel of oil any of my competitors ship with you.”
Rockefeller succeeded in getting much lower transportation costs,
allowing him to undercut his competitors. When they started
going
under, he’d by up their stock. Then, with monopoly control,
he’d
jack up the prices: no competition anymore! In this way,
Rockefeller ended up controlling most of the nation’s oil
production. And he got away with such shenanigans by bribing
legislators. “Standard oil did everything to the Ohio
legislature
except refine it.”
Free enterprise, or big-business connivance to destroy competition
and
prevent the growth of true free enterprise? I would say the
latter.